第118章(1 / 1)
Even if global
regulation can't do much good, at least, it is argued, it cannot do any harm.
But in fact it can. Regulation, by its nature, inhibits freedom of market action,
and that freedom to act expeditiously is what rebalances markets.
489
THE AGE OF TURBULENCE
Undermine this freedom and the whole market-balancing process is put at
risk. We never, of course, know all the many millions of transactions that
occur every day. Neither does a U.S. Air Force B-2 pilot know, or need to
know, the millions of automatic split-second computer-based adjustments
that keep his aircraft in the air.
In today's world, I fail to see how adding more government regulation
can help. Collecting data on hedge fund balance sheets, for example, would
be futile, since the data would probably be obsolete before the ink dried.
Should we set up a global reporting system of the positions of hedge and
private equity funds to see if there are any dangerous concentrations that
could indicate potential financial implosions? I have been dealing with financial
market reports for almost six decades. I would not be able to judge
from such reports whether concentrations of positions reflected markets
in the process of doing what they are supposed to do—remove imbalances
from the system—or whether some dangerous trading was emerging. I
would truly be surprised if anyone could.
To be sure, the "invisible hand" presupposes that market participants
act in their self-interest, and there are occasions when they do take demonstrably
stupid risks. For example, I was shaken by the recent revelation that
dealers in credit default swaps were being dangerously lax in keeping detailed
records of the legal commitments that stemmed from their over-thecounter
transactions. In the event of a significant price change, disputes
over contract language could produce a real but unnecessary crisis.* This
episode was a problem not of market price risk but of operational risk—
that is, the risks associated with a breakdown in the infrastructure that enables
markets to function.
Superimposed on the longer-term forces I've discussed, it is important
to remember, is the business cycle. It is not dead, even though it has been
muted for the past two decades. There is little doubt that the emergence of
just-in-time inventory programs and increasing service output has markedly
diminished the amplitude of fluctuations in GDP. But human nature
does not change. History is replete with waves of self-reinforcing enthusi
*Fortunately, with the assistance of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, this particular
problem is on its way to being solved.
490
TH E DE LPH IC FUTU RE
asm and despair, innate human characteristics not subject to a learning
curve. Those waves are mirrored in the business cycle.
Taken together, the financial problems confronting the next quarter
century do not make a pretty picture. Yet we have lived through far worse.
None of them will permanently undermine our institutions, or even likely
topple the U.S. economy from its place of world leadership. Indeed there
are currently a number of feared financial imbalances that are likely to be
resolved with far less impact on U.S. economic activity than is generally
supposed. I indicated in chapter 18 that the unwinding of our current account
deficit is not likely to have a major impact on economic activity or
employment. The fear that a liquidation of much of China's and Japan's
huge foreign-exchange reserves will drive U.S. interest rates sharply higher
and dollar exchange rates lower is also exaggerated.
There is little we can do to avoid the easing of global disinflationary
forces. I view that as a return to fiat-money normalcy not a new aberration.
What is more, we have it within our power to sharply mitigate some of the
more dire features of the scenario I have outlined above. First, the president
and Congress must not interfere with the Federal Open Market Committee's
efforts to contain the inevitable inflationary pressures that will eventually
emerge (the members will need no encouragement). Monetary policy
can simulate the gold standard's stable prices. Episodes of higher interest
rates will be required. But the Volcker Fed demonstrated that it can be done.
Second, the president and Congress must make certain that the economic
and financial flexibility that enabled the U.S. economy to absorb the
shock of 9/11 is not impaired. Markets should remain free to function
without the administrative constraints—particularly those on wages, prices,
and interest rates—that have disabled them in the past. This is especially
important in a world of massive movements of funds, huge trading volumes,
and markets rendered inevitably opaque by their increasing complexity.
Economic and financial shocks will occur: human nature, with its
fears and its foibles, remains a wild card. The resulting shocks will, as always,
be difficult to anticipate, so the ability to absorb them is a paramount
requirement for stability of output and employment.
Hands-on supervision and regulation—the twentieth-century financial
model—is being swamped by the volume and complexity of twenty-first
491
THE AGE OF TURBULENCE
century finance. Only in areas of operational risk and business and consumer
fraud do the principles of twentieth-century regulation remain intact. Much
regulation will continue to be aimed at ensuring that rapid-fire; risk-laden
dealings are financed by wealthy professional investors, not by the general
public. Efforts to monitor and influence market behavior that is proceeding
at Mach speeds will fail. Public-sector surveillance is no longer up to the
task. The armies of examiners that would be needed to maintain surveillance
on today's global transactions would by their actions undermine the
financial flexibility so essential to our future. We have no sensible choice
other than to let markets work. Market failure is the rare exception, and its
consequences can be assuaged by a flexible economic and financial system.
H
H
owever we get to 2030, the U.S. economy should end up much larger,
absent unexpectedly long crises—three-fourths larger in real terms
than that in which we operate today. What's more, its output will be far
more conceptual in nature. The long-standing trend away from value produced
by manual labor and natural resources and toward the intangible
value-added we associate with the digital economy can be expected to continue.
Today it takes a lot less physical material to produce a unit of output
than it did in generations past. Indeed, the physical amount of materials
and fuels either consumed in the production of output or embodied in the
output has increased very modestly over the past half century. The output
of our economy is not quite literally lighter, but it is close.
Thin fiber-optic cable, for instance, has replaced huge tonnages of copper
wire. New architectural, engineering, and materials technologies have
enabled the construction of buildings enclosing the same space with far less
physical material than was required fifty or one hundred years ago. Mobile
phones have not only downsized but also morphed into multipurpose communication
devices. The movement over the decades toward production of
services that require little physical input has also been a major contributor
to the marked rise in the ratio of constant dollars of GDP to tons of input.
If you compare the dollar value of the gross domestic product—that is,
the market value of all goods and services produced—of 2006 with the
GDP of 1946, after adjusting for inflation, the GDP of the country over
492
TH E DE LPH IC FUTU RE
which George W. Bush presides is seven times larger than Harry Truman's.
The weight of the inputs of materials required to produce the 2006 output,
however, is only modestly greater than was required to produce the 1946
output. This means that almost all of the real-value-added increases in our
output reflect the embodiment of ideas.
The dramatic shift during the past half century toward the less tangible
and more conceptual—the amount of weight the economy has lost, as it
were—stems from several causes. The challenge of accumulating physical
goods in an ever more crowded geographical environment has clearly resulted
in pressures to economize on size and space. Similarly, the prospect
of increasing costs of discovering, developing, and processing ever-larger
quantities of physical resources in less amenable terrain has raised marginal
costs and shifted producers toward downsized alternatives. Moreover, as
the technological frontier has moved forward and pressed for information
processing to speed up, the laws of physics have required microchips to become
ever more compact.
The new downsized economy operates differently from its predecessors.
In the typical case of a manufactured good, the incremental cost of increasing
output by one unit ultimately rises as production expands. In the
realm of conceptual output, however, production is often characterized by
constant, and often negligible, marginal cost. Though the setup cost of creating
an online medical dictionary, for instance, may be huge, the cost of reproduction
and distribution may be near zero if the means of distribution is
the Internet. The emergence of an electronic platform for the transmission
of ideas at negligible marginal cost is doubtless an important factor explaining
the most recent increased conceptualization of the GDP. The demand
for conceptual products is clearly impeded to a much lesser degree by rising
marginal cost and, hence, price, than is the demand for physical products.
The high cost of developing software and the negligible production and,
if online, distribution costs tend to suggest a natural monopoly—a good
or service that is supplied most efficiently by one firm. A stock exchange is
an obvious example. It is most efficient to have all the trading of a stock
concentrated in one market. Bid-asked spreads narrow and transaction
costs decline. In the 1930s, Alcoa was the sole U.S. producer of raw aluminum.
It kept its monopoly by passing on, in ever-lower prices, almost all its
493
THE AGE OF TURBULENCE
increases in efficiency. Potential competitors could not envision an acceptable
rate of return if they had to match Alcoa's low prices.*
Today's version of that aspiring natural monopoly is Microsoft, with its
remarkable dominance in personal computer operating systems. Getting
into a market early with the capability to define a new industry's template
fends off potential competitors. Creating and cultivating this lock-in effect
is thus a prime business strategy in our new digital world. Despite this advantage,
Microsoft's natural monopoly has proved far from absolute. The
dominance of its Windows operating system has been eroded by competition
from Apple and open-source Linux. Natural monopolies, in the end,
are displaced by technological breakthroughs and new paradigms.
Strategies come and go, but the ultimate competitive goal remains:
gaining the maximum rate of return, adjusted for risk. Competition effectively
works, whatever the strategy, provided free and open markets prevail.
Antitrust policy, never in my judgment an effective procompetition tool, is
going to find its twentieth-century standards far out of date for the new
digital age, in which an innovation can turn an eight-hundred-pound gorilla
into a baby chimpanzee overnight.1
The trend toward conceptual products is irreversibly increasing the
emphasis on intellectual property and its protection—a second area of
the law that is likely to be challenged. The president's Council of Economic
Advisors in early 2006 cited output by industries "highly dependent on
patent.. . and copyright protection," such as pharmaceuticals, informa
nt is often said that many companies do lower prices in an attempt to drive competitors out
of business. But unless their costs are persistently lower than competitors', this is a losing strategy.
To raise prices after potential competitors retire from the market is decidedly short-sighted.
Despite claims that it is a common practice, I have seen very little of it in my six decades observing
business. It is an effective way to lose customers.
tAntitrust policy in the United States was born in the nineteenth century and evolved in
twentieth-century law in reaction to allegations of price fixing and other transgressions contrary
to then current views of how markets should work. I have always thought the competitive
model employed by the courts to judge infractions was not one that maximized economic efficiency.
I fear that applying that twentieth-century model to markets of the twenty-first century
will be even more counterproductive. Freeing up markets by withdrawing subsidies and anti-
competition regulation, in my judgment, has always been the most effective antimonopoly
policy
494
TH E DE LPH IC FUTU RE
tion technology, software, and communications, as accounting for almost a
fifth of U.S. economic activity in 2003. The council also estimated that a
third of market value of publicly traded U.S. corporations in September
2005 ($15 trillion) was attributable to intellectual property; of that third,
software and other copyright-protected materials represented nearly two-
fifths, patents a third, and trade secrets the remainder. It is almost certainly
the case that intellectual property's share of stock-market value is much
larger than its share of economic activity. Industries with disproportionately
large shares of intellectual property are also the most rapidly growing
industries in the U.S. economy. I see no obstacle to intellectual property's
share of GDP rising into 2030.*
Before World War I, markets in the United States were essentially
uninhibited by government regulations, but were supported by rights to
property, which in those years largely meant physical property. Intellectual
property—patents, copyrights, and trademarks—represented a far less important
aspect of the economy. One of the most significant inventions of
the nineteenth century was the cotton gin: perhaps it was a sign of the
times that the cotton gin design was never effectively protected.
Only in recent decades, as the economic product of the United States
has become so predominantly conceptual, have issues related to the protection
of intellectual property rights come to be seen as significant sources
of legal and business uncertainty. In part, this uncertainty derives from the
fact that intellectual property is importantly different from physical property.
Because physical assets have a material existence, they are more capable
of being defended by police or private security forces. By contrast,
intellectual property can be stolen by an act as simple as publishing an idea
without the permission of the originator. Significantly, one individual's use
of an idea does not make that idea unavailable to others for their own simultaneous
use.
Even more to the point, new ideas—the building blocks of intellectual
Th e major loser of GDP share by 2030 is likely to be U.S. manufacturing (excluding high
tech). Moreover, continued productivity growth will further shrink the number of jobs in
manufacturing
495
THE AGE OF TURBULENCE
property—almost invariably build on old ideas in ways that are difficult or
impossible to trace. From an economic perspective, this provides a rationale
for making calculus, developed initially by Newton and Leibniz, freely
available, despite the fact that the insights of calculus have immeasurably
increased wealth over the generations. Should the law have protected
Newton's and Leibniz's claims in the same way that we do those of owners
of land?