第113章(1 / 1)
As a newly anointed Fed chairman, I was watching
the markets very closely. What new piece of information surfaced
between the market's close at the end of the previous trading day and its
close on October 19? I am aware of none. As prices careened downward
all that day, human nature, in the form of unreasoning fear, took hold, and
investors sought relief from pain by unloading their positions regardless
of whether it made financial sense. No financial information was driving
those prices. The fear of continued loss of wealth had simply become
465
THE AGE OF TURBULENCE
unbearable.* And while the economy and corporate profits subsequently
advanced, it took nearly two years for the Dow to recover fully.
When markets are behaving rationally, as they do almost all the time,
they appear to engage in a "random walk": the past gives no better indication
than a coin flip of the future direction of the price of a stock. But sometimes
that walk is interrupted by a stampede. When gripped by fear, people rush to
disengage from commitments, and stocks will plunge. And when people are
driven by euphoria, they will drive up prices to nonsensical levels.
So the key question remains, as I summarized it in a 1996 reflection I
shall never live down, "How do we know when irrational exuberance has
unduly escalated asset values, which then become subject to unexpected
and prolonged contractions?" It is often suggested that the richest investors
are those best at gauging shifts in human psychology rather than at forecasting
earnings per share of ExxonMobil. A whole school of stock-market
psychologists has arisen around this thesis. They call themselves Contrarians.
They trade on the view that irrational exuberance eventually ends up
in falling stock prices, as shares get bid up for no plausible reason, and then,
when that becomes evident, fear grips the market and prices unravel. Contrarians
pride themselves on trading against crowd psychology. Since stock
prices are cyclical, some do succeed by trading contrary to the crowd. But
you rarely hear about those who try this approach and lose their shirts. I
also never hear much from coin tossers who lose.
Perhaps someday investors will be able to gauge when markets veer from
the rational and turn irrational. But I doubt it. Inbred human propensities to
swing from euphoria to fear and back again seem permanent: generations of
experience do not appear to have tempered those propensities. I would think
that we learn from experience, and, in one sense, we do. I, for example, when
asked what worrisome imbalances and problems lie over the forecast horizon,
invariably respond that financial crises that are foreseeable by market
participants rarely happen. If a stock-market bulge is perceived to be the
precursor of a crash, speculators and investors will try to sell out earlier. That
defuses the nascent bubble and a crash is avoided. The sudden eruptions of
*I find the oft-quoted explanation that it was program trading unconvincing. As prices tumbled,
sellers could have turned off the program-trading switch.
466
TH E DE LPH IC FUTU RE
fear or euphoria are phenomena that nobody anticipates. The horrendous
decline in stocks on "Black Monday" came out of the dark.
Successful investing is difficult. Some of history's most successful investors,
such as my friend Warren Buffett, were early to understand the
now well-documented anomaly that the rate of return on stocks, even adjusted
for risk, exceeds that on less-risky bonds and other debt instruments,
provided one is willing to buy and hold equities for the very long run. "My
favorite holding period is forever," said Buffett in an interview. The market
pays a premium to those willing to endure the angst of watching their net
worth fluctuate beyond what Wall Streeters call the "sleeping point."
The lessons of stock-market investing apply to the forecasting of whole
economies. Because markets tend to steady themselves, a market economy
turns out to be more stable and forecastable over the long run than in the
short run鈥攁ssuming, of course, that the society and institutions upon which
it rests remain stable. Long-term economic forecasting is grounded in two
sets of historically stable data: (1) population, which is the most forecastable
statistic with which economists deal, and (2) productivity growth, the consequence
of the incremental buildup of knowledge and the source of sustainable
growth. Since knowledge is never lost, productivity will always rise.*
What, then, can we reasonably project for the U.S. economy for, say,
the year 2030?