首页 > 其他 > 格林斯潘自传:动荡年代(The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a > 第38章

第38章(1 / 1)

目 录
好书推荐: 格瑞特妖怪学院 对不起,爱到你 孤魂公主 绾绾 浩然正气之重出江湖 异姓封王 邪意未来 小白兔与大灰狼的故事 帘卷海棠红 借种小老公

I asked. Klaus cut

me short. "In your country you can afford such luxuries/' he said. "To succeed

we need a clean break with the past. The competitive market is the

way to produce wealth, and that's where we're going to focus." He and I

became good friends, but this was the first time in my life that I had ever

been rebuked for not sufficiently appreciating the power of free markets. It

was a singular experience for an admirer of Ayn Rand.

A

A

s the Eastern European countries raced ahead with reform, the instability

in Moscow only seemed to worsen. It was hard from the West

even to determine what was going on. Just a week after being elected president

of the Russian Republic in June 1991, Boris Yeltsin visited New York

and spoke at the New York Fed. Yeltsin had gotten his start as a construction

industry boss and had been Moscow's mayor in the 1980s; then he'd

quit the Communist Party to take up the cause of radical reform. His election

with a nationwide majority of 60 percent was a crushing defeat for Communism.

Though he was subordinate to Gorbachev, his popularity coupled

with his impetuousness made him a magnet for attention鈥攍ike Khrushchev

in an earlier era, he seemed to personify his country's unnerving contradictions.

His first trip to the United States in 1989 had been a disaster鈥攑eople

remembered mostly the news reports of his behaving erratically and getting

drunk on Jack Daniel's.

Gerald Corrigan, the president of the New York Fed, had taken the

lead in encouraging Wall Street to connect with the Soviet reformers, something

the Bush administration wanted to see happen. So when Yeltsin came

to town, the New York Fed invited him to speak at a dinner of some fifty

bankers, financiers, and corporate chiefs. Yeltsin arrived with a large entourage,

and Corrigan and I talked with him briefly before he was introduced to

the assembled dinner guests. The Yeltsin we met that night was no drunken

buffoon; he seemed smart and determined. At the podium, he spoke co

134

TH E FALL OF TH E WALL

gently on reform for twenty minutes without notes and then answered detailed,

specific questions from the audience without calling on his advisers

for help.

It was increasingly unclear whether Gorbachev, or anyone, could end

the Communist regime without causing a complete collapse into violence.

After Gorbachev dissolved the Warsaw Pact in June and launched his plan

to reconstitute the USSR as a voluntary confederation of democratic states,

the resistance facing him became brutally apparent. In August a coup attempt

by Stalinist hard-liners almost brought him down鈥攖o many it was

only the inspired theatrics of Yeltsin, who climbed on a tank outside the

Soviet parliament, that enabled Gorbachev to survive.

The West started looking for ways to help. That was the reason Treasury

Secretary Nick Brady and I led a team to Moscow in September to

meet with Gorbachev and confer with his economic advisers. Our ostensible

mission was to assess what reforms were needed for the Soviet Union

to join the International Monetary Fund, but mainly we wanted to see for

ourselves what was going on.

From the perspective of the Fed and the Western world, in purely economic

terms the Soviet Union was not much of a concern. Its economy

wasn't that large; of course there were no reliable statistics, but experts estimated

its GDP to be about the same size as the United Kingdom's, or

about one-sixth the size of all Europe's. The iron curtain had kept it so isolated

that its share of world trade was small. So was the amount of debt it

owed Western nations, which might be subject to default if the government

collapsed. But none of this took into account nuclear warheads. We were all

acutely aware of the danger a Soviet collapse could pose to the world's stability

and safety.

For that reason alone, we were horrified by the picture that emerged

during our stay.

It was clear that the government was falling apart. The institutions of

central planning were all beginning to fail, and the well-being of the population

was threatened. Eduard Shevardnadze, who was then foreign minister,

told us of unrest in the Soviet republics along Russia's border鈥攈e said the

lives of the twenty-five million ethnic Russians living in those regions could

135

THE AGE OF TURBULENCE

be in jeopardy. Worse, he said, was the risk that Russia and Ukraine, which

both held weapons from the Soviet nuclear arsenal, might end up at odds.

The economic data, which were fragmentary at best, were equally

alarming. Inflation was out of control, with prices going up by anywhere

from 3 percent to 7 percent a week. This was because all of the central

mechanisms of production and distribution were breaking down, and more

and more money was chasing fewer and fewer goods. In an effort to keep

things moving at all, the government was flooding the economy with cash.

A Gorbachev aide told me, "The printing presses can't keep up. We are

printing rubles twenty-four hours a day."

Over all this hung the shadow of not being able to put food on the

shelves. There had been times in the past when the output of Ukraine had

made it famous as the breadbasket of the world. But while harvests were

still relatively bountiful, some of the crops had rotted in the fields because

there was no way to collect and distribute the produce and grain. Soviet

grain purchases from abroad were up to forty million tons a year. Bread

shortages were a sore point in the national memory鈥攊t was the Bread Riots

of 1917, when the old women of St. Petersburg rose up in rebellion, that

helped bring about the fall of the czar.

A separate conversation gave me a glimpse of how brittle this economy

was and how difficult it would be to change. Boris Nemtsov, a reformist

economist, confided, "Let me tell you about military cities," and rattled off

names I'd never heard of. Across the nation, Nemtsov explained, were at

least twenty cities, each of two million people or more, that had been built

around military plants. They were isolated and specialized and had no reason

to exist other than to serve the Soviet military. His point was clear:

ending the cold war, and shifting to a market economy, would leave entire

cities and millions of workers with little to do and no ready way to adapt.

The rigidity built into the Soviet economic system was far more extreme

than any we'd ever encountered in the West. Among the many worries was

that, in order to survive, these military workers, who included world-class

scientists and engineers and technicians, would eventually have to sell their

skills to rogue states.

There were more briefings, but the message was the same. When we

met with President Gorbachev, and he repeated his goal of making the

136

TH E FALL OF TH E WALL

nation "a major trading force in the world/' I admired his courage. But in

the margin of my notepad I jotted down, "USSR is a Greek tragedy waiting

to happen."

G

G

rigory Yavlinsky chief economist for Gorbachev's Council of Minis

ters, led a delegation in October 1991 to Thailand, where the World

Bank and International Monetary Fund were holding their annual meeting.

This was a truly historic moment: the first time Soviet officials had ever sat

down with the key economic policymakers of the capitalist world.

The Soviet Union had already been granted provisional status鈥攆ormally

giving it access to IMF and World Bank advice, but not to loans. Yavlinsky

and his team came to argue that the confederation of remaining Soviet re

publics ought to be accorded full membership. The question of massive

Western loans was not immediately on the table鈥攖he Soviets insisted they

could manage the transition to a market economy themselves, and none of

the G7 nations was offering.

The discussions lasted two full days, and if I had to pick a word to describe

what the Western central bankers and finance ministers felt, it would

be "impotence." We knew that what was left of the Soviet Union was crumbling;

we knew the armed forces hadn't been paid and that a collapse of the

military could pose a serious threat to world peace. We had grave concerns

about what would happen to the nuclear weapons. The deterioration was

internal and political. All the IMF could do was talk about money, and

money wasn't the problem. We ended up doing what organizations usually

do under such circumstances: we delegated a committee for further study

and discussion (in this instance, the deputy finance ministers of the G7

were to go to Moscow in a few weeks for consultations). So it was up to the

Soviet reformers. The challenges they faced were more difficult than those

that had confronted their counterparts in Eastern Europe. The Polish and

Czech leaders had been able to draw on the goodwill of the population鈥攁s

trying as the economic circumstances may have been, their nations were

being liberated from Moscow's grasp. But many Soviet citizens had prided

themselves on their country's superpower status and had sacrificed much

to help achieve it. For them, the upheavals meant nothing but sorrow鈥攁

137

THE AGE OF TURBULENCE

great loss of national prestige. Humiliation made the reformers' tasks much

harder.

What's more, too many years had gone by in the Soviet Union since

1917鈥攕carcely anyone alive even remembered private property or had

firsthand business experience or training. There were no accountants, auditors,

financial analysts, marketers, or commercial lawyers, even among retirees.

In Eastern Europe, where Communism had reigned for forty years

instead of eighty, free markets could be restored; in the Soviet Union, they

had to be resurrected from the dead.

Gorbachev did not stay in power long enough to oversee the market

reforms; he resigned in December 1991 as the Soviet Union formally broke

up and was replaced by a loose economic confederation of former Soviet

republics. "End of the Soviet Union; Gorbachev, Last Soviet Leader, Resigns;

U.S. Recognizes Republics' Independence" read the headline of the

New York Times on December 26鈥擨 looked at it and felt regret that Ayn

Rand hadn't lived to see it. She and Ronald Reagan had been among the

few who had predicted decades before that the USSR would ultimately

collapse from within.

The man Boris Yeltsin chose to launch economic reforms in Russia was

Yegor Gaidar. In the 1980s when he and other young economists had

dreamed of creating a market economy in the Soviet Union, they'd imagined

an organized, methodical transition. But now, amid growing chaos,

there was no time for that鈥攗nless the government could jump-start the

markets, people might starve. So in January 1992, Gaidar, as Russia's acting

prime minister, turned to the scheme that had worked in Poland: abruptly

ending price controls.

Shock therapy jolted the Russians much more than it had the Poles.

The size of the country, the system's rigidity, the fact that the state had dictated

prices for people's entire lives鈥攊t all worked against them now. Inflation

rose so fast that people's wages, when they could collect them, became

worthless, and their meager savings were wiped out. The ruble lost three

quarters of its value in four months. Goods remained in scarce supply in

the stores, and the black market flourished.

Then, in October, Yeltsin and his economists unleashed the second

massive reform: they issued vouchers to 144 million citizens and started

138

TH E FALL OF TH E WALL

privatizing state-owned enterprises and real estate on a massive scale. This

reform, too; was far less effective than in Eastern Europe. Millions of people

ended up with stock in businesses or owning their apartments, which was

the goal, but millions more were bilked out of their vouchers. Entire industries

ended up in the hands of a small number of opportunists who came to

be known as the oligarchs. Like Jay Gould and some of the railroad tycoons

in nineteenth-century America who built vast fortunes in part by manipulating

government land grants, the oligarchs constituted an entirely new

wealthy class and compounded the political chaos.

I

I

was fascinated to see these events unfold. Economists have had considerable

experience observing how market economies convert to centrally

planned ones鈥攊ndeed, the shift toward Communism in the East and socialism

in the West was the dominant economic trend of the twentieth

century. Yet until recent years we have had little exposure to movement in

the opposite direction. Until the wall fell and the need to develop market

economies out of the rubble of Eastern Europe's central-planning regimes

became apparent, few economists had been thinking about the institutional

foundations that free markets need. Now, unintentionally, the Soviets were

performing an experiment for us. And some of the lessons were startling.

The collapse of central planning did not automatically establish capitalism,

contrary to the rosy predictions of many conservative-leaning politicians.

Western markets have a vast underpinning of culture and infrastructure

that has evolved over generations: laws, conventions, behaviors, and business

professions and practices for which there was no need in a centrally

planned state.

Forced to make the shift overnight, the Soviets achieved not a free-

market system but a black-market one. Black markets, with their unregulated

prices and open competition, seemingly replicate what goes on in a

market economy. But only in part. They are not supported by the rule of

law. There is no right to own and dispose of property backed up by the enforcement

power of the state. There are no laws of contract or bankruptcy,

and no opportunity to take disputes to court for resolution. The linchpin of

a free-market economy, property rights, is missing.

139

THE AGE OF TURBULENCE

The result is that black markets bring few of the benefits to society of

legally sanctioned trade. Knowing that the government will protect one's

property encourages citizens to take business risks, a prerequisite of wealth

creation and economic growth. Few will risk their capital if the rewards are

going to be subject to arbitrary seizure by the government or mobsters.

By the mid-1990s, that was the picture across much of Russia. For generations

of people who had been brought up on the Marxist notion that

private property is theft, the shift to a market economy already challenged

their sense of right and wrong.* The rise of the oligarchs further undermined

popular support. From the start, law enforcement in defense of private

ownership was extremely uneven. Private security forces to a large

extent took over the job, sometimes warring with each other and further

aggravating the sense of chaos.

It wasn't at all clear that the Yeltsin government itself understood how

a market economy's legal system must work. In 1998, for instance, an influential

Russian academic told the Washington Post: "The state thinks .. . private

capital should be defended by those who have it.... It's a completely

conscious policy of the law enforcement authorities to remove themselves

from defending private capital." To me this suggested a basic ignorance of

the need to embody property rights in the judicial system. The use of rival

private police forces is not the rule of law; it is the rule of fear and force.

Trust in the word of others, especially strangers, was another element

conspicuously lacking in the new Russia. We hardly ever think about this

facet of market capitalism, yet it is crucial. Despite each person's right in

the West to file a lawsuit to address a perceived grievance, if more than a

small fraction of contracts were adjudicated, our courts would be swamped

to the point of paralysis. In a free society, the vast majority of transactions

are thus, of necessity, voluntary. Voluntary exchange, in turn, presupposes

*Marx was hardly the first to condemn private ownership; the notion that private property is

sinful, along with profit making and lending at interest, has deep roots in Christianity, Islam,

and other religions. Only with the Enlightenment did countervailing principles emerge to provide

a moral basis for ownership and profit. John Locke, the great seventeenth-century British

philosopher, wrote of the "natural right" of every individual to "life, liberty and estate." Such

thinking profoundly influenced America's Founding Fathers and helped foster free-market

capitalism in the United States.

140

TH E FALL OF TH E WALL

trust. I have always been impressed that in Western financial markets, transactions

involving hundreds of millions of dollars often are simply oral

agreements that get confirmed in writing only at a later date, and at times

after much price movement. But trust has to be earned; reputation is often

the most valuable asset a business has.

T

T

he fall of the Soviet Union concluded a vast experiment: the long

standing debate about the virtues of economies organized around free

markets and those governed by centrally planned socialism is essentially at

an end. To be sure, there are still a few who support old-fashioned social

ism. But what the vast majority of the remaining socialists now advocate is

a highly diluted form, often called market socialism.

I am not alleging that the world is about to embrace market capitalism

as the only relevant form of economic and social organization. Vast num

bers of people still consider capitalism with its emphasis on materialism

degrading. And one can seek material well-being and yet view competitive

markets as subject to excessive manipulation by advertisers and marketers

who trivialize life by promoting superficial and ephemeral values. Some

governments, such as that of China, even now attempt to override the evi

dent preferences of their citizens by limiting their access to foreign media,

which they fear will undermine their culture. Finally, there remains a latent

protectionism, in the United States and elsewhere, which could emerge as

a potent force against international trade and finance and the free-market

capitalism they support, particularly if today's high-tech world economy

should falter. Nonetheless, the verdict on central planning has been ren

dered, and it is unequivocally negative.

141

SEVEN

A DEMOCRAT'S

AGENDA

O

O

n the evening of February 17,1993,1 found myself in the uncomfortable

glare of the TV lights at a joint session of Congress,

sitting between Hillary Clinton and Tipper Gore. The front row

of the gallery was not exactly where I'd expected to be for President Clin

ton's first major congressional address. I had assumed that my invitation to

sit with the First Lady was a matter of courtesy and that I'd be at the back

of the box with White House aides. I guess it was nice to know that the

Federal Reserve was considered a valuable national asset after the some

what less than favorable embrace we'd gotten from President Bush, but

obviously I'd been positioned up front for a political purpose. Mrs. Clinton

was wearing a bright red suit, and as the president spoke, the cameras fo

cused on us again and again.

Afterward it turned out that not everyone had been pleased to see me

there, on the grounds that it might compromise the independence of the

Fed. I had no intention of doing that, of course. But I was intent on building

a working relationship with this president, who seemed seriously fiscally

responsible.

A DEMOCRAT'S AGENDA

I'd met Clinton in early December, when he was president-elect. He

hadn't moved to Washington yet, so seeing him meant flying out to Little

Rock, Arkansas. He and his transition team had set up shop there in the

governor's mansion, which turned out to be a big redbrick building with

white pillars set on acres of flat lawn and gardens near the center of town.

As I was ushered into an anteroom, I wasn't sure what to expect. One

thing I'd heard, though, was that he always ran late, so I'd brought along

some economic reports to read and busied myself for twenty minutes or so

until he appeared. "Mr. Chairman," he said, striding toward me smiling and

reaching to shake hands. I could see why he was reputed to be a great retail

politician. He made me believe he really had been looking forward to seeing

me.

Clinton had outlined a broad, ambitious economic agenda during his

campaign. He wanted to cut taxes on the middle class, halve the federal

deficit, stimulate job growth, increase U.S. competitiveness through new

education and training programs, invest in the nation's infrastructure, and

more. I had seen, and been part of, too many presidential campaigns. Candidates

promised something for everybody. But I wondered what Clinton's

real priorities were. He must have been reading my mind; one of the first

things he said was: "We need to set our economic priorities, and I'm interested

in your outlook on the economy."

From the Fed's perspective, if he wanted to address the economy's

long-term health, the deficit was by far the most pressing concern. I'd made

that argument at the start of Bush's term, and now the problem was four

years worse. The national debt held by the public had risen to $3 trillion,

causing interest payments to become the third-largest federal expense after

Social Security and defense. So when Clinton asked for my economic assessment,

I was ready with a pitch.

Short-term interest rates were rock-bottom low鈥攚e'd cut them to 3

percent鈥攁nd the economy was gradually shaking off the effects of the

credit crunch and growing at a fairly reasonable pace, I told him. More than

a million net new jobs had been created since the beginning of 1991. But

long-term interest rates were still stubbornly high. They were acting as a

brake on economic activity by driving up the costs of home mortgages and

143

THE AGE OF TURBULENCE

bond issuance. They reflected an expectation of ongoing inflation for which

investors had come to require an extra margin of interest to offset the

added uncertainty and risk.

Improve investors' expectations, I told Clinton, and long-term rates

could fall, galvanizing the demand for new homes and the appliances, furnishings,

and the gamut of consumer items associated with home ownership.

Stock values, too, would rise, as bonds became less attractive and

investors shifted into equities. Businesses would expand, creating jobs. All

told, the latter part of the 1990s could look awfully good. I was not oblivious

of the fact that 1996 would be a presidential election year. The path to

a beneficent future, I told the president-elect, was lowering the long-term

trajectory of federal budget deficits.

To my delight, Clinton seemed fully engaged. He seemed to pick up on

my sense of urgency about the deficit, and asked a lot of smart questions

that politicians usually don't ask. Our meeting, which had been scheduled

for an hour, turned into a lively discussion that went on for almost three.

We touched on a whole range of topics beyond economics鈥擲omalia and

Bosnia and Russian history, job-training programs, education鈥攁nd he asked

for my assessment of world leaders whom he hadn't yet had a chance to

meet. After a while, aides brought in lunch.

So saxophone wasn't the only thing we had in common. Here was a

fellow information hound, and like me, Clinton clearly enjoyed exploring

ideas. I walked away impressed, yet not entirely sure what I thought. Clearly,

for sheer intelligence, Bill Clinton was on a par with Richard Nixon, who,

despite his obvious flaws, was the smartest president I'd met to that point.

And either Clinton shared many of my views on the way the economic system

was evolving and on what should be done, or he was the cleverest chameleon

I'd ever encountered. I mulled all this on the airplane on my way

home. After I got back to Washington, I told a friend, "I don't know that I'd

have changed my vote, but I'm reassured."

That feeling was reinforced a week later when Clinton announced as

his senior economic team a number of familiar faces. As treasury secretary

he'd picked Lloyd Bentsen, the chairman of the Senate Finance Committee,

with Roger Altman, a very smart Wall Street investment banker, as his

deputy. As budget director he chose Leon Panetta, a California congressman

144

A DEMOCRAT'S AGENDA

who chaired the House Budget Committee, with economist Alice Rivlin as

his deputy. She was the only economist on the team, and her credentials

were impressive: she'd been the founding director of the Congressional

Budget Office and had been an early recipient of one of the MacArthur

Foundation's genius grants. Just as interesting was Clinton's choice of Robert

Rubin, the cochairman of Goldman Sachs, to run a new White House

council on economic policy. As the New York Times explained it, Rubin was

to act as the economic equivalent of a national security adviser: his job

would be to elicit economic ideas from Treasury, State, the budget office,

the CEA, and other departments, and weave them into policy options for

the president. What jumped out at me was that Clinton was taking a page

from John F. Kennedy's book. All of Clinton's economic-policy appointees

were fiscally conservative centrists like Doug Dillon, the Republican banker

whom Kennedy picked as treasury secretary. Choosing them made Bill

Clinton seem about as far from the classic tax-and-spend liberal as you

could get and still be a Democrat.

L

L

ike every new administration, the Clinton White House had to scramble

to pull together its first budget, due for submission to Congress by

early February. The president by all accounts did not have an easy time

dealing with the recommendations of his economic team. The full extent

of the fiscal problems confronting them was only now becoming clear: in

December the Office of Management and Budget offered a revised analysis

projecting that the government was headed toward a $360 billion deficit

in 1997鈥攕ome $50 billion higher than its previous estimate. This made

it clear that to come anywhere near his goal of halving the deficit, Clinton

would have to abandon or postpone other cherished plans, such as the

middle-class tax cut and the "investments" in training and jobs.

I kept tabs on the budget-making process mainly through Lloyd Bentsen.

The new treasury secretary had first caught my attention in the 1976

primaries鈥擩immy Carter ultimately beat him for the Democratic nomination,

but I thought Bentsen had looked like a president and acted like one.

Courtly, gray-haired, and sophisticated, he was a former World War II B-24

bomber pilot who'd served four terms in the Senate, where he had a well

145

THE AGE OF TURBULENCE

earned reputation for good judgment and for quietly getting things done.

Andrea and I had known Bentsen and his impressive wife, B.A., socially for

some time. I was not surprised to find him a pleasure to work with, even

when we disagreed.

Bentsen and the others on the economic team were careful to acknowledge

the Fed's boundaries. In fact, their decision not to comment publicly

on monetary policy was a big break from the past, and helped us and them

by bolstering our independence. When he and Panetta came to brief me in

mid-January on the evolving budget plan, they avoided asking for an endorsement

or even an opinion. I simply indicated that I understood, and we

left it at that. In fact, I thought the plan noninflationary and testified to that

effect in Congress in late January.

Bentsen asked me to weigh in with the president just once鈥攖he day

after I'd first testified in favor of their overall approach. (I had steered clear

of commenting on the details of Clinton's program.) As the team crunched

the numbers and the budget took shape, Clinton found himself faced with

a choice that was increasingly stark. Either he could opt for a package of

spending programs that would fulfill some of his campaign promises, or he

could opt for a deficit-cutting plan, whose success would depend on impressing

the financial markets and that would pay off chiefly in the longer

term. There was no in-between鈥攚e couldn't afford both. This dilemma

had opened a rift in the White House staff, some of whom privately ridiculed

the deficit-cutting approach as a sellout to Wall Street. That's why

Bentsen asked me to the White House鈥攖o reemphasize the urgency of

budget reform.

We met the president in the Oval Office on the morning of January 28;

Bob Rubin joined us. Clinton was all business, so I got straight to the point.

I focused on the danger of not confronting the deficit right away, playing

out for him how, in that instance, the decade was apt to unfold. Because

of the end of the cold war, I told him, "defense spending will come down

over the next few years and that will mask a lot of problems. But by 1996

or 1997, the deficits will be hard for the public to ignore. You can see it in

the data." And I outlined for him how the mandated outlays for Social Security

and other social benefits were scheduled to increase, which would

146

A DEMOCRAT'S AGENDA

cause deficit gaps to open further. "So the debt rises markedly into the

twenty-first century, and the interest on the debt rises, threatening a spiral

of rising deficits. Unless it's aborted, that could lead to a financial crisis," I

said. As we finished, Clinton, unsurprisingly, looked grim.

Though I hadn't put it in so many words, the hard truth was that Reagan

had borrowed from Clinton, and Clinton was having to pay it back.

There was no reason to feel sorry for Clinton鈥攖hese very problems were

what had enabled him to defeat George Bush. But I was impressed that he

did not seem to be trying to fudge reality to the extent politicians ordinarily

do. He was forcing himself to live in the real world on the economic

outlook and monetary policy. His subsequent decision to go ahead and

fight for the deficit cuts was an act of political courage. It would have been

very easy to go the other way. Not many people would have been the wiser

for a year or two or even three.

I took one other step to help the deficit hawks鈥擨 advised Bentsen on

how deeply I thought the deficit would have to be cut in order to convince

Wall Street and thereby bring down long-term interest rates. "Not less than

$130 billion a year by 1997" was his shorthand description of what I said.

Actually the advice I gave him was more complex. I sketched out a range

of possibilities, with a probability attached to each鈥攁ll the while carefully

emphasizing that the substance and credibility of the program would be

more important than the numbers. But I understood when he finally said,

"You know I can't work with something this complicated." The figure he

extracted made its way to the president and had a powerful effect. Within

the White House, $130 billion became known as the "magic number" that

the deficit cuts had to hit.

The budget was major news when it finally appeared. "Clinton Plan to

Remake the Economy Seeks to Tax Energy and Big Incomes" was the banner

headline of the New York Times the morning after Clinton's speech.

"Ambitious Program Aims at a 4-Year Deficit Cut of $500 Billion." USA Today

declared "A Battle Launched" and described Clinton's proposals as "a

five-year package of pain." The media coverage focused mainly on whom

the cuts would hit (every constituency except poor households鈥攖he plan

put burdens on the rich, the middle class, retirees, and business). Interest

147

THE AGE OF TURBULENCE

ingly, the public reaction was initially favorable: polls showed Americans

unexpectedly receptive to the idea of making a sacrifice to put the nation's

house in order.

Most new presidents get a honeymoon from Congress, but Clinton got

a trench war. Despite the budget plan's initial popularity a majority of

congresspeople hated it鈥攏ot surprisingly, since it aimed at abstract, distant

goals and offered no new highway projects, weapons programs, or other lucrative

goodies to bring home to constituents. I think Clinton was jolted by

the degree of resistance. Republicans rejected the budget outright and

many Democrats rebelled, and the debates dragged on well into the spring.

Even though Democrats held a 258-177 majority in the House, there was

serious question whether the budget would pass鈥攁nd its prospects in the

Senate looked even worse. The conflict extended to within the White

House, where key people were still pushing for an agenda less compatible

with Wall Street. One was Clinton adviser James Carville, who famously

wisecracked, "I used to think if there was reincarnation, I wanted to come

back as the president or the pope or a .400 baseball hitter. But now I want

to come back as the bond market. You can intimidate everybody." The discord,

which was widely reported in the media, made Clinton look weak,

and his initial popularity melted away. By late spring his approval rating

sank to an abysmal 28 percent.

The president was in a funk when I saw him again on June 9. The

House had finally passed his budget two weeks earlier鈥攂y a single vote.

And the fight had only begun in the Senate. I'd gotten a call from David

Gergen, Clinton's counselor. "He's distressed," he said, and asked if I could

come buck the president up. I'd known Gergen for twenty years, as an adviser

to Nixon, Ford, and Reagan. Clinton had recruited him partly because

he was a balanced, nonneurotic Washington pro, and partly because he was

Republican鈥攖he president was hoping to solidify his image as a centrist.

When I went to the Oval Office that morning, you could see that people

were under strain. Word had it that they'd been working pretty much

around the clock, even Bentsen, who was seventy-two. (Andrea confirmed

this; she was now NBC's chief White House correspondent.) They'd been

going back and forth with Congress, trying to get the numbers to work, and

148

A DEMOCRAT'S AGENDA

doubtless felt as if they were up against an impossible problem. The president

himself seemed subdued. It wasn't hard to imagine why. He was

spending his political capital, yet the budget for which he'd sacrificed so

much was in peril.

I encouraged him as best I could. I told him that his plan was our best

chance in forty years to get stable long-term growth. I tried to get him to

see that the strategy was on track, was working鈥攍ong-term rates were already

trending down, I showed him. The very fact that he'd come out and

recognized that the deficit had to be addressed was a very important plus.

But I also warned that it wouldn't be easy. Indeed, Clinton had to fight,

arm-twist, and horse-trade for another two months to push his budget

through the Senate. As in the House, it passed by a single vote鈥攖his time a

tiebreaker by Vice President Gore.

Clinton impressed me again that fall by fighting for the ratification of

NAFTA. The treaty, negotiated under President Bush, was designed primarily

to phase out tariffs and other trade barriers between Mexico and the

United States, though it also included Canada. Labor unions hated it, and

so did most Democrats, as well as some conservatives; few Congress watchers

thought it had a prayer. But Clinton argued, in effect, that you cannot

stop the world from turning; like it or not, America was increasingly part of

the international economy, and NAFTA embodied the belief that trade and

competition create prosperity, and you need free markets to do that. He

and the White House staff went all out, and after a two-month struggle

they got the treaty approved.

All this convinced me that our new president was a risk taker who was

not content with the status quo. Again he'd shown a preference for dealing

in facts. And on free trade, the fact was this: The distinction between domestic

competition and cross-border competition has no economic meaning.

If you're in a Dubuque, Iowa, plant, it makes no difference whether

you're competing with someone in Santa Fe or across the border. With the

geopolitical pressure of the cold war now removed, the United States had

a historic opportunity to knit the international economy more closely together.

Clinton was often criticized for inconsistency and for a tendency to

take all sides in a debate, but that was never true about his economic policy.

149

THE AGE OF TURBULENCE

A consistent, disciplined focus on long-term economic growth became a

hallmark of his presidency.

T

T

he Fed was having its own difficulties with Congress that year, and for

some of the same reasons. Our fiercest critic was Congressman Henry B.

Gonzalez of Texas, the chairman of the House Banking Committee. A hot-

tempered populist from San Antonio, Gonzalez was famous for socking in

the eye a constituent at a restaurant who called him a Communist. At vari

ous times in Congress, Gonzalez had called for the impeachment of Rea

gan, Bush, and Paul Volcker. He was deeply distrustful of what he labeled

"the tremendous power of the Fed"鈥擨 think he simply assumed that the

Board was a cabal of Republican appointees who were running monetary

policy more for the benefit of Wall Street than the workingman. In the fall

of 1993, Gonzalez really turned up the heat.

The Fed has always rubbed Congress the wrong way, and it probably

always will, even though Congress created it. There's inherent conflict be

tween the Fed's statutory long-term focus and the short-term needs of

most politicians with constituents to please.

This friction often surfaced in oversight hearings. The Fed was obli

gated to render a biannual report on its monetary-policy decisions and the

economic outlook. At times these hearings sparked substantive discussions

of major issues. But just as often they were a theater in which I was a

prop鈥攖he audience was the voters back home. During the Bush adminis

tration, Senate Banking Committee chairman Alfonse D'Amato of New

York rarely missed a chance to bash the Fed. "People are going to starve out

there, and you are going to be worried about inflation," he'd tell me. That

sort of remark I always let slide. But when he or anyone would assert that

interest rates were too high, I would answer and explain why we'd done

what we'd done. (I took care, naturally, to couch any discussion of possible

future moves in Fedspeak to keep from roiling the markets.)

Gonzalez went on a crusade to make the Fed more accountable, zeroing

in on what he saw as our excessive secrecy. He wanted the Federal

Open Market Committee, in particular, to conduct its affairs in public, and

even open its deliberations to live TV coverage. At one point he dragged

150

A DEMOCRAT'S AGENDA

eighteen members of the FOMC to Capitol Hill to testify under oath and

denounced the long-standing FOMC practice of never publicly announcing

policy moves or rate changes. The only public record of each meeting was

a brief set of minutes published six weeks after the fact鈥攆or the financial

markets, a virtual eternity. As a consequence, any signals coming from the

Fed's open-market operations, or public statements by Fed officials, were

subject to avid scrutiny by Wall Street.

For its part, the Federal Reserve, in the interest of economic stability, had

long sought to foster highly liquid debt markets through the use of what we

called constructive ambiguity. The idea was that markets uncertain as to the

direction of interest rates would create a desired large buffer of both bids and

offers. By the early 1990s, however, markets were becoming sufficiently

broad and liquid without this support from the Fed. Moreover, the advantage

of market participants being able to anticipate the Federal Reserve's future

moves was seen as stabilizing the debt markets. We had begun a path toward

greater transparency in our deliberations and operations, but far short of the

policy Henry Gonzalez would have liked us to pursue.

I was opposed to the idea of throwing these meetings open. The FOMC

was our primary decision-making body. If its discussions were made public,

with the details of who said what to whom, the meetings would become a

series of bland, written presentations. The advantages to policy formulation

of unfettered debate would be lost.

My effort to convey this argument in the hearings, however, did not go

well. As Gonzalez bored in on the question of what records we kept, I

found myself in an extremely awkward position. In 1976, during the Ford

administration, Arthur Burns had directed the staff to audiotape FOMC

meetings to assist in the writing of the minutes. This practice continued,

and I knew about it, but I'd always assumed the tapes were erased once the

minutes were done. In preparing for the Banking Committee testimony, I

learned that this wasn't exactly the case: although the tapes indeed were

routinely erased, the staff kept copies of the complete unedited transcripts

in a locked file cabinet down the hall from my office. When I revealed the

transcripts' existence, Gonzalez pounced. Now more convinced than ever

that we were conspiring to hide embarrassing secrets, he threatened to

subpoena the records.

151

THE AGE OF TURBULENCE

Gonzalez was especially suspicious of two conference calls the FOMC

had conducted in preparing for the hearings. We did not want to release

these tapes, for fear of creating a precedent. After a bit of negotiation,

we agreed to let lawyers for the committee鈥攐ne Democrat and one

Republican鈥攃ome to the Fed and listen.

The Watergate tapes had been a lot more exciting, they quickly discovered.

After listening patiently for the better part of two hours to the

FOMC's deliberations, the Democrat left without a word, and the Republican

remarked that the tape ought to be used to teach students in high

school civics classes how government meetings should work.*

All the same, my colleagues were upset鈥攎ainly with Gonzalez, but

they probably weren't too happy with me either. For one thing, most of them

hadn't even known our meetings were being taped. And the thought that

any remarks they now made might be published immediately if Gonzalez

got his way put a chill in the air. The next time the FOMC met, on November

16, people were clearly less willing to kick around ideas. "You could notice

a difference, and not for the better," a governor told a Washington Post

reporter.

After thorough discussion, the Board decided to resist, in court if

necessary, any subpoena or demand that might hamper the effectiveness of

the institution. But the controversy also accelerated our recent deliberations

about transparency. Eventually we decided that the FOMC would

announce its moves immediately after each meeting and that the complete

transcript would be published after a five-year lag. (People joked that this

was the Fed equivalent of glasnost.) We did these things knowing that

published transcripts made our meetings longer and a little less creative. In

the event, the sky did not fall. Not only did the changes make the process

more transparent but they also gave us new ways to communicate with the

markets.

I was grateful that President Clinton kept his distance from this whole

*Congressman Gonzalez was quoted in the New York Times (November 16, 1993) complaining

that the tapes included "disparaging remarks about one distinguished member of the House

Banking Committee and Banking Committee members in general."

152

A DEMOCRAT'S AGENDA

teapot tempest. "Does anybody in his right mind think we would do anything

to change the independence of the Fed?"

目 录
新书推荐: 天与咒缚弱?我怒开八门遁甲! 大秦:始皇大大是我爹! 被赵王赶走,始皇拜我为丞相 离婚后,我权势滔天,你哭什么 剑修,狗都不谈 开局红警基地,你却让我拍电影? [红楼]升官发财娶黛玉 引诱清冷权臣后 人在现实,但有鼠符咒! 亡妻回归的方式不太对
返回顶部